Thursday, January 13, 2011
Cricket and the Arts
"What is Art?".
This is the provocative question posed by CLR James in his magnificent book Beyond the Boundary, widely regarded as the finest cricket book of all time. James attempts to answer this question in a manner which is much too elaborate to be summed up in a blogpost. Nevertheless, he unequivocally concludes that :
These lines intrigued me. Cricket is ofcourse a ball game. But is it fundamentally different from the other ball games? Are we justified in regarding cricket as being closer to the arts (the likes of theatre and literature) than other sports?
I attempt to partly answer these questions in this blog. To my mind, there is one chief characteristic that distinguishes all ball games from the arts:
Ball Games are invariably competitive, in that the performance of the sportsman is contingent on the opposition he is up against. Whereas, in most of the other conventional arts, the performance of the artist is nearly independent of practically everything else.
For instance, Pele scored 1,280 goals in his career over 1,363 games. That's an average of 0.94 goals per game. Suppose Pele had played all his football in the Indian leagues (which are distinctly less competitive), one would naturally expect that average to have been significantly higher (perhaps 1.5 or more).
On the other hand, our appraisal of an artist in the theatre or in the cinema is absolute and is hardly contingent on the prevailing competition or standards.
Now, let us examine the game of cricket. To what extent are performances in cricket dependent on the quality of the opposition? I believe that cricket is closer to the arts than other ball games in this respect. Cricketing feats, be it batting or bowling, are less sensitive to "opposition quality" than feats in soccer or rugby.
Does that sound counter-intuitive? On the surface, Yes. But not if one examines closely the records of great cricketers, past and present.
Let us start with bowling. Below, I have looked at the bowling averages of five great modern bowlers both in Tests and first-class cricket.
It is quite clear that all five bowlers have very similar averages both in Test matches and in First-class cricket. Let us suppose a hypothetical bowling attack comprising these five bowlers. Given that their mean Test average is 23.13, we can expect an average Test-class batting lineup to score 231 runs (23.13 X 10) against this attack. Whereas, an average First-class batting lineup (presumably consisting of relatively inferior batsmen) can be expected to score 222 runs (22.2 X 10) against the same bowlers!
The learning is that the wicket taking ability of these five men is almost independent of the standard of cricket being played. It is quite unlikely that these bowlers are any deadlier in a First-class fixture than in a Test match. In fact, we can infer that the bowling average is very close to being a measure of the intrinsic wicket-taking worth of a bowler. A bowler's average is unlikely to change too much across eras and different playing standards.
What about batting then? Is the career batting average very sensitive to the quality of the bowling attacks faced? The answer is No. Below, I have a similar list contrasting the Test careers of several top modern batsmen with their First-class careers.
Again, we notice that a batsman is quite likely to have similar averages both in Tests and First-class games. In fact, it is quite common to observe cases where the first-class average is lower than the Test average since it is a lot harder to sustain a high batting average over a very large number of first-class fixtures.
I find these tables very revealing. They do suggest how very different cricket is from other ball games. Unlike most other games, performance in cricket is purely a function of the cricketer's inherent skill and not overly influenced by the playing standards of the opposition.
Which is why, it is possible to argue that a cricketer is closer in spirit to a ballet dancer or a movie star than to a soccer player or a rugby forward.
Also, cricket lends itself to comparisons across eras unlike other sports. No serious tennis buff would want to argue too strongly that Bill Tilden transported from the 1920s and equipped with modern raquets would be able to defeat Roger Federer today. The reason is that modern tennis players train harder and are more athletic than champions of yesteryear. In a very physical sport like tennis, training and "professionalism" matter a LOT.
Cricket, on the other hand, is different. Being a skill-based sport, it places less premium on training and athleticism than most other sports. Secondly, the nature of the game is such that it tests one's character as much as skill. If you're a batsman, it only takes one ball to get you out. This holds true regardless of whether it is a Test match at the MCG or a University game in New Delhi. It doesn't matter whether the cricketer in question is WG Grace in 1870 or Viru Sehwag in 2010. It only takes one ball to get you out!!
To my mind, that's the reason why standards in cricket unlike other ball games do not always improve with time. For instance, fast-bowling talent today is most definitely not as rich across the world as it was in the early 1980s. Similarly, the art of leg-spin in the 1970s was surely not as advanced or as prevalent as it was in the 1930s.
Like the other art forms, cricketing standards are subject to crests and troughs. In this regard, it is fundamentally different from most other sports where standards invariably improve with time.
Also, it is possible to think of a batsman or a bowler as an artist in isolation. It is also possible to measure a cricketer's worth by examining his numbers without bothering to consider the numbers of anyone else!
Cricket sure is a very unique game! A veritable art form? Well, very nearly!
|
"What is Art?".
This is the provocative question posed by CLR James in his magnificent book Beyond the Boundary, widely regarded as the finest cricket book of all time. James attempts to answer this question in a manner which is much too elaborate to be summed up in a blogpost. Nevertheless, he unequivocally concludes that :
It (cricket) is a game and we have to compare it with other games. It is an art and we have to compare it with other arts.....Cricket is first and foremost a dramatic spectacle. It belongs with the theatre, ballet, opera and the dance
These lines intrigued me. Cricket is ofcourse a ball game. But is it fundamentally different from the other ball games? Are we justified in regarding cricket as being closer to the arts (the likes of theatre and literature) than other sports?
I attempt to partly answer these questions in this blog. To my mind, there is one chief characteristic that distinguishes all ball games from the arts:
Ball Games are invariably competitive, in that the performance of the sportsman is contingent on the opposition he is up against. Whereas, in most of the other conventional arts, the performance of the artist is nearly independent of practically everything else.
For instance, Pele scored 1,280 goals in his career over 1,363 games. That's an average of 0.94 goals per game. Suppose Pele had played all his football in the Indian leagues (which are distinctly less competitive), one would naturally expect that average to have been significantly higher (perhaps 1.5 or more).
On the other hand, our appraisal of an artist in the theatre or in the cinema is absolute and is hardly contingent on the prevailing competition or standards.
Now, let us examine the game of cricket. To what extent are performances in cricket dependent on the quality of the opposition? I believe that cricket is closer to the arts than other ball games in this respect. Cricketing feats, be it batting or bowling, are less sensitive to "opposition quality" than feats in soccer or rugby.
Does that sound counter-intuitive? On the surface, Yes. But not if one examines closely the records of great cricketers, past and present.
Let us start with bowling. Below, I have looked at the bowling averages of five great modern bowlers both in Tests and first-class cricket.
Mean Bowling Averages | ||
---|---|---|
Tests | First-class | |
Shane Warne | 25.41 | 26.11 |
Wasim Akram | 23.62 | 21.64 |
Allan Donald | 22.25 | 22.76 |
Glenn McGrath | 21.64 | 20.85 |
Muthiah Muralitharan | 22.72 | 19.64 |
Overall Average | 23.13 | 22.2 |
It is quite clear that all five bowlers have very similar averages both in Test matches and in First-class cricket. Let us suppose a hypothetical bowling attack comprising these five bowlers. Given that their mean Test average is 23.13, we can expect an average Test-class batting lineup to score 231 runs (23.13 X 10) against this attack. Whereas, an average First-class batting lineup (presumably consisting of relatively inferior batsmen) can be expected to score 222 runs (22.2 X 10) against the same bowlers!
The learning is that the wicket taking ability of these five men is almost independent of the standard of cricket being played. It is quite unlikely that these bowlers are any deadlier in a First-class fixture than in a Test match. In fact, we can infer that the bowling average is very close to being a measure of the intrinsic wicket-taking worth of a bowler. A bowler's average is unlikely to change too much across eras and different playing standards.
What about batting then? Is the career batting average very sensitive to the quality of the bowling attacks faced? The answer is No. Below, I have a similar list contrasting the Test careers of several top modern batsmen with their First-class careers.
Mean Batting Averages | ||
---|---|---|
Tests | First-class | |
Sachin Tendulkar | 56.94 | 59.86 |
Brian Lara | 52.88 | 51.88 |
Steve Waugh | 51.06 | 51.94 |
Kumar Sangakkara | 57.25 | 48.01 |
Kevin Pietersen | 48.42 | 49.01 |
Again, we notice that a batsman is quite likely to have similar averages both in Tests and First-class games. In fact, it is quite common to observe cases where the first-class average is lower than the Test average since it is a lot harder to sustain a high batting average over a very large number of first-class fixtures.
I find these tables very revealing. They do suggest how very different cricket is from other ball games. Unlike most other games, performance in cricket is purely a function of the cricketer's inherent skill and not overly influenced by the playing standards of the opposition.
Which is why, it is possible to argue that a cricketer is closer in spirit to a ballet dancer or a movie star than to a soccer player or a rugby forward.
Also, cricket lends itself to comparisons across eras unlike other sports. No serious tennis buff would want to argue too strongly that Bill Tilden transported from the 1920s and equipped with modern raquets would be able to defeat Roger Federer today. The reason is that modern tennis players train harder and are more athletic than champions of yesteryear. In a very physical sport like tennis, training and "professionalism" matter a LOT.
Cricket, on the other hand, is different. Being a skill-based sport, it places less premium on training and athleticism than most other sports. Secondly, the nature of the game is such that it tests one's character as much as skill. If you're a batsman, it only takes one ball to get you out. This holds true regardless of whether it is a Test match at the MCG or a University game in New Delhi. It doesn't matter whether the cricketer in question is WG Grace in 1870 or Viru Sehwag in 2010. It only takes one ball to get you out!!
To my mind, that's the reason why standards in cricket unlike other ball games do not always improve with time. For instance, fast-bowling talent today is most definitely not as rich across the world as it was in the early 1980s. Similarly, the art of leg-spin in the 1970s was surely not as advanced or as prevalent as it was in the 1930s.
Like the other art forms, cricketing standards are subject to crests and troughs. In this regard, it is fundamentally different from most other sports where standards invariably improve with time.
Also, it is possible to think of a batsman or a bowler as an artist in isolation. It is also possible to measure a cricketer's worth by examining his numbers without bothering to consider the numbers of anyone else!
Cricket sure is a very unique game! A veritable art form? Well, very nearly!
Labels: cricket
Saturday, November 27, 2010
On Risk, Return and Batsmanship
In Finance, one of the cardinal sins is to undertake an investment decision without assessing the forecasted return in the context of the risk exposure. Risk and Return are inextricably linked. I'd rather have my money earn 3.5% in the Savings account if an alternative market investment promises a 10% return with a standard deviation of 50%!
A common metric often employed to evaluate portfolio performance is the Sharpe Ratio, which is basically the premium return that is offered by an investment for each unit of risk undertaken. No wonder "risk-adjusted return" is a hackneyed phrase one hears from portfolio managers.
How is all this related to Test Match Batsmanship? Very closely related as we shall see.
Batsmen in Test Matches are often judged on the basis of their "batting average". An average of 50+ is usually regarded as outstanding and is often the figure that most Test batsmen aspire for. Ofcourse, one needs considerable skill to maintain an average of over 50. But more than skill, I think the key is to understand risk-return dynamics well.
There are two components to the batting average that ought to be understood if one wishes to optimize it:
Sounds too obvious, yes. But this is not exactly a simple plain-vanilla two-variable function. What's often overlooked by batsmen and cricket pundits is that A and B are not independent variables. A is a function of B and vice-versa.
In fact, the two components influence each other negatively. Typically, a batsman with a high strike rate spends less time in the middle, because of the risks involved in trying to force the pace. Similarly, a batsman who bats for long periods of time tends to have a lower strike rate, for reasons that are obvious.
So what should one do to optimize the Batting Average? Should the batsman adopt a risk-averse style by concentrating only on putting away the rank bad ball and defending the rest? The likes of Hutton, Gavaskar and Dravid have achieved great Test records by optimising Component A, without overly worrying about Component B. Nevertheless, for every Gavaskar, there are a dozen other fine technicians who couldn't reach the magic figure of 50 despite their excellence at Component A. Geoff Boycott is a name that readily springs to mind.
There are others who have Test records just as enviable as those of a Gavaskar or a Dravid thanks to their extraordinary strike rates. Viru Sehwag is an obvious example. Here's a guy who is a very limited batsman in many ways, with serious technical deficiencies against the short rising ball. A guy who lasts only 64 balls each time he comes in to bat (that's probably about half the number of balls per innings faced by someone like Gavaskar). And yet, he has a brilliant batting average of 54, significantly better than Gavaskar's 51!! The secret of his success is that he manages to maintain a strike-rate of 80 and yet lasts 64 balls per innings!
There have been several daredevil strokeplayers in the past who have graced the game of cricket. Think Gilbert Jessop, Kris Srikkanth and more recently Shahid Afridi. All of them had batting averages significantly below 40. This is because their high-risk approach to the game significantly reduced their average duration at the crease.
The reason why Sehwag is such a great treasure is not because he is a great strokemaker (there have been several such players in the past) or a great technician (which is hardly the case). Sehwag's greatness lies in his ability to understand the dynamics of risk and return. He is able to play his normal game without taking undue risks that were the bane of players like Afridi or Yuvraj Singh.
It is vital for batsmen around the world to grasp the importance of maximising risk-adjusted returns. The tradeoff between risk and return may vary among batsmen depending on their skill level. Yet, the magnitude of the tradeoff can be minimised only if you are aware of the tradeoff in the first place!
Take Dravid for instance. The man averages a fantastic 53 with a strike rate of about 42 per 100 balls faced. He roughly faces 110 balls each time he visits the crease in a Test match. I'd like to argue that he has not consciously thought about the tradeoff during his career. For a batsman of his ability, the tradeoff between strike-rate and duration at the crease shouldn't be too large.
Mathematically, the tradeoff can be stated as shown below :
The objective should be to minimise the absolute value of the above differential!
Cutting down the aerial strokes to the extent possible and running well between the wickets are some of the ways of achieving this objective.
Let us suppose Dravid had been a little more aggressive during his Test career and maintained a strike-rate of 50 instead of 42. This might have reduced his "No of balls per innings" figure from 110 to perhaps 100. Nevertheless, it is a great trade-off. His hypothetical batting average in this case is 56.5, a good three runs higher than his current average! (Note: I'm assuming the same no of "Not out" innings as before)
The man widely regarded as the greatest batsman in Test history is ofcourse Sir Donald Bradman. People often have endless debates on what made him so special. The Don was a somewhat frail man with poor eyesight. In fact, he came perilously close to losing his life on account of poor health during his career. By most accounts, he wasn't a particularly "correct" batsman, with a very unusual grip and a notorious tendency to play across the line. Yet, he averaged 99.94 in Tests and more astonishingly 95.14 in all first-class cricket!
The secret to his success is that like Sehwag, he understood the risk-return tradeoff probably better than most people. No wonder he was a professional stock-broker off the field. The Don managed to maintain a strike-rate of 60 in Test matches (astonishingly high back in the thirties) and lasted about 145 balls per innings.
The figure of 145 is not as exceptional as his batting average. It's still probably better than the Component A of most other batsmen in Test history. But I'm sure there are several bastsmen who are running him close. What made him special was his ability to score at a strike rate as high as 60 without compromising on the time spent in the middle.
I know this post may sound a tad too obvious to a lot of people. But I think it bears repeating. The Risk-return tradeoff is something we're all aware of, yet we don't always consciously think of optimising it in the daily business of life!
|
In Finance, one of the cardinal sins is to undertake an investment decision without assessing the forecasted return in the context of the risk exposure. Risk and Return are inextricably linked. I'd rather have my money earn 3.5% in the Savings account if an alternative market investment promises a 10% return with a standard deviation of 50%!
A common metric often employed to evaluate portfolio performance is the Sharpe Ratio, which is basically the premium return that is offered by an investment for each unit of risk undertaken. No wonder "risk-adjusted return" is a hackneyed phrase one hears from portfolio managers.
How is all this related to Test Match Batsmanship? Very closely related as we shall see.
Batsmen in Test Matches are often judged on the basis of their "batting average". An average of 50+ is usually regarded as outstanding and is often the figure that most Test batsmen aspire for. Ofcourse, one needs considerable skill to maintain an average of over 50. But more than skill, I think the key is to understand risk-return dynamics well.
There are two components to the batting average that ought to be understood if one wishes to optimize it:
Component A : Time Spent in the Middle i.e the No of balls that one lasts on an average per innings
Component B : The ability to force the pace while in the Middle. This component is better known as "Strike rate" i.e the No of runs that one scores per 100 balls faced.
Batting Average = F(Component A, Component B)
Sounds too obvious, yes. But this is not exactly a simple plain-vanilla two-variable function. What's often overlooked by batsmen and cricket pundits is that A and B are not independent variables. A is a function of B and vice-versa.
In fact, the two components influence each other negatively. Typically, a batsman with a high strike rate spends less time in the middle, because of the risks involved in trying to force the pace. Similarly, a batsman who bats for long periods of time tends to have a lower strike rate, for reasons that are obvious.
So what should one do to optimize the Batting Average? Should the batsman adopt a risk-averse style by concentrating only on putting away the rank bad ball and defending the rest? The likes of Hutton, Gavaskar and Dravid have achieved great Test records by optimising Component A, without overly worrying about Component B. Nevertheless, for every Gavaskar, there are a dozen other fine technicians who couldn't reach the magic figure of 50 despite their excellence at Component A. Geoff Boycott is a name that readily springs to mind.
There are others who have Test records just as enviable as those of a Gavaskar or a Dravid thanks to their extraordinary strike rates. Viru Sehwag is an obvious example. Here's a guy who is a very limited batsman in many ways, with serious technical deficiencies against the short rising ball. A guy who lasts only 64 balls each time he comes in to bat (that's probably about half the number of balls per innings faced by someone like Gavaskar). And yet, he has a brilliant batting average of 54, significantly better than Gavaskar's 51!! The secret of his success is that he manages to maintain a strike-rate of 80 and yet lasts 64 balls per innings!
There have been several daredevil strokeplayers in the past who have graced the game of cricket. Think Gilbert Jessop, Kris Srikkanth and more recently Shahid Afridi. All of them had batting averages significantly below 40. This is because their high-risk approach to the game significantly reduced their average duration at the crease.
The reason why Sehwag is such a great treasure is not because he is a great strokemaker (there have been several such players in the past) or a great technician (which is hardly the case). Sehwag's greatness lies in his ability to understand the dynamics of risk and return. He is able to play his normal game without taking undue risks that were the bane of players like Afridi or Yuvraj Singh.
It is vital for batsmen around the world to grasp the importance of maximising risk-adjusted returns. The tradeoff between risk and return may vary among batsmen depending on their skill level. Yet, the magnitude of the tradeoff can be minimised only if you are aware of the tradeoff in the first place!
Take Dravid for instance. The man averages a fantastic 53 with a strike rate of about 42 per 100 balls faced. He roughly faces 110 balls each time he visits the crease in a Test match. I'd like to argue that he has not consciously thought about the tradeoff during his career. For a batsman of his ability, the tradeoff between strike-rate and duration at the crease shouldn't be too large.
Mathematically, the tradeoff can be stated as shown below :
d(No of Balls per innings)/d(Strike Rate) <= 0
The objective should be to minimise the absolute value of the above differential!
Cutting down the aerial strokes to the extent possible and running well between the wickets are some of the ways of achieving this objective.
Let us suppose Dravid had been a little more aggressive during his Test career and maintained a strike-rate of 50 instead of 42. This might have reduced his "No of balls per innings" figure from 110 to perhaps 100. Nevertheless, it is a great trade-off. His hypothetical batting average in this case is 56.5, a good three runs higher than his current average! (Note: I'm assuming the same no of "Not out" innings as before)
The man widely regarded as the greatest batsman in Test history is ofcourse Sir Donald Bradman. People often have endless debates on what made him so special. The Don was a somewhat frail man with poor eyesight. In fact, he came perilously close to losing his life on account of poor health during his career. By most accounts, he wasn't a particularly "correct" batsman, with a very unusual grip and a notorious tendency to play across the line. Yet, he averaged 99.94 in Tests and more astonishingly 95.14 in all first-class cricket!
The secret to his success is that like Sehwag, he understood the risk-return tradeoff probably better than most people. No wonder he was a professional stock-broker off the field. The Don managed to maintain a strike-rate of 60 in Test matches (astonishingly high back in the thirties) and lasted about 145 balls per innings.
The figure of 145 is not as exceptional as his batting average. It's still probably better than the Component A of most other batsmen in Test history. But I'm sure there are several bastsmen who are running him close. What made him special was his ability to score at a strike rate as high as 60 without compromising on the time spent in the middle.
I know this post may sound a tad too obvious to a lot of people. But I think it bears repeating. The Risk-return tradeoff is something we're all aware of, yet we don't always consciously think of optimising it in the daily business of life!
Saturday, November 20, 2010
Ranji - the most underrated cricketer of all time?
The name Ranji immediately conjures up a smallish brown man of royal lineage who lit up the English cricket fields with his brilliantly unorthodox strokeplay about a hundred and ten years ago. He is widely regarded as one of the game's great early innovators and a very popular cricketer in England at the turn of the century.
But pundits don't normally invoke Ranji seriously while discussing all-time greats. Recently, Cricinfo picked an "All-Time XI" for each of the major international Test playing countries. I was flabbergasted to learn that Ranji was not even nominated as a middle-order choice for the All-Time England XI!!
English cricket lovers are not exactly known for their ahistoricism, unlike Indian fans who tend to focus on the here and now. It is very hard to find any English cricket writer who hasn't turned in a few lines on the likes of WG Grace, Sidney Barnes, Gilbert Jessop, Jack Hobbs among others. In fact, Wisden went to the extent of picking Hobbs as one of the five greatest cricketers of the Twentieth century!
Being an Indian with a fair share of interest in English cricket, I wondered - Where does Ranji rank in the pantheon of great English cricketers? Is he widely known today primarily on account of his exotic Indian origin? Are we guilty of overrating his stature in the context of English cricket history? After all, he was the first person of colour to play Test match cricket.
I turned to Cricinfo Statsguru to better understand Ranji in terms of hard numbers. The idea was to move beyond the romantic prose penned by the cricket writers of his time and judge the man using figures alone.
What one discovers is a true cricketing colossus!
Here is a man who played First class cricket in England for 25 years spanning from 1895 to 1920. A man who scored nearly 25,000 First class runs at an average of 56.37!! (yes, you read that right) These figures are very impressive even by today's English first class standards, notwithstanding the fact that English pitches in Ranji's time were a lot livelier by most accounts, even when unaffected by rain. Just to put that average into perspective, Graeme Hick, the most prolific English first class batsman of the past 20 years averages 52.
During his time, Ranji played Test match cricket with/against names like Grace, Trumper, Jessop, Fry and Hobbs among others. All these guys represented the cream of talent the world had on offer during that period. How does Ranji compare with each of them?
I must say Ranji trumps them all going by the first class averages. In fact, he is miles ahead of the rest.
It is a very revealing table! Ranji is about 6 runs ahead of the next best batsman. That's a really huge margin. The most striking revelation is that Ranji averaged a good 17 runs more than the great WG in his First class career and about 12 runs more than the celebrated Australian legend - Vic Trumper.
The two guys who approach him in consistency are Jack Hobbs and CB Fry. However, Hobbs scored the bulk of his runs post WW-I during the twenties, when batting became a lot easier thanks to the improved pitches of the time. It is quite likely that Hobbs averaged well below 50 if one considers only his pre WW-I record. CB Fry had an outstanding First class record, but disappointed in Test cricket with an average of barely 32.
How does Ranji rank among all the great first-class cricketers of the past 150 years?
To attempt an answer to this question, I looked at the top 10 batsmen with the highest first-class averages in cricket history (with a minimum run aggregate of atleast 20,000 runs). Ranji ranks sixth in this list.
Ranji is the only person on this list who made his first-class debut prior to 1920. In fact, he played nearly all his cricket before World War I. Now that was an era when an average of 35-40 used to be regarded as a very good record in first-class cricket.
I think these tables ought to be better known. Ranji was so much more than a mystical Oriental talent who played unorthodox strokes. He was, without doubt, the foremost batsman of his generation. In fact, it can be argued that Ranji was the most dominant and consistent batsman the world had seen until Bradman came along in the thirties.
Surely it's a career that deserves more recognition by cricket historians and greater mindshare among cricket fans (especially English cricket fans)!
|
The name Ranji immediately conjures up a smallish brown man of royal lineage who lit up the English cricket fields with his brilliantly unorthodox strokeplay about a hundred and ten years ago. He is widely regarded as one of the game's great early innovators and a very popular cricketer in England at the turn of the century.
But pundits don't normally invoke Ranji seriously while discussing all-time greats. Recently, Cricinfo picked an "All-Time XI" for each of the major international Test playing countries. I was flabbergasted to learn that Ranji was not even nominated as a middle-order choice for the All-Time England XI!!
English cricket lovers are not exactly known for their ahistoricism, unlike Indian fans who tend to focus on the here and now. It is very hard to find any English cricket writer who hasn't turned in a few lines on the likes of WG Grace, Sidney Barnes, Gilbert Jessop, Jack Hobbs among others. In fact, Wisden went to the extent of picking Hobbs as one of the five greatest cricketers of the Twentieth century!
Being an Indian with a fair share of interest in English cricket, I wondered - Where does Ranji rank in the pantheon of great English cricketers? Is he widely known today primarily on account of his exotic Indian origin? Are we guilty of overrating his stature in the context of English cricket history? After all, he was the first person of colour to play Test match cricket.
I turned to Cricinfo Statsguru to better understand Ranji in terms of hard numbers. The idea was to move beyond the romantic prose penned by the cricket writers of his time and judge the man using figures alone.
What one discovers is a true cricketing colossus!
Here is a man who played First class cricket in England for 25 years spanning from 1895 to 1920. A man who scored nearly 25,000 First class runs at an average of 56.37!! (yes, you read that right) These figures are very impressive even by today's English first class standards, notwithstanding the fact that English pitches in Ranji's time were a lot livelier by most accounts, even when unaffected by rain. Just to put that average into perspective, Graeme Hick, the most prolific English first class batsman of the past 20 years averages 52.
During his time, Ranji played Test match cricket with/against names like Grace, Trumper, Jessop, Fry and Hobbs among others. All these guys represented the cream of talent the world had on offer during that period. How does Ranji compare with each of them?
I must say Ranji trumps them all going by the first class averages. In fact, he is miles ahead of the rest.
First-class Averages of Ranji and his Contemporaries | ||
---|---|---|
Ranji | 56.37 | |
Jack Hobbs | 50.70 | |
CB Fry | 50.22 | |
Charles MaCartney | 45.78 | |
Vic Trumper | 44.57 | |
Clem Hill | 43.57 | |
Frank Woolley | 40.77 | |
WG Grace | 39.45 | |
Archie MacLaren | 34.15 | |
Gilbert Jessop | 32.63 |
It is a very revealing table! Ranji is about 6 runs ahead of the next best batsman. That's a really huge margin. The most striking revelation is that Ranji averaged a good 17 runs more than the great WG in his First class career and about 12 runs more than the celebrated Australian legend - Vic Trumper.
The two guys who approach him in consistency are Jack Hobbs and CB Fry. However, Hobbs scored the bulk of his runs post WW-I during the twenties, when batting became a lot easier thanks to the improved pitches of the time. It is quite likely that Hobbs averaged well below 50 if one considers only his pre WW-I record. CB Fry had an outstanding First class record, but disappointed in Test cricket with an average of barely 32.
How does Ranji rank among all the great first-class cricketers of the past 150 years?
To attempt an answer to this question, I looked at the top 10 batsmen with the highest first-class averages in cricket history (with a minimum run aggregate of atleast 20,000 runs). Ranji ranks sixth in this list.
Highest First-class Averages of all Time (Qual.criteria : 20,000 runs) | ||
---|---|---|
Don Bradman | 95.14 | |
Sachin Tendulkar | 59.63 | |
Darren Lehmann | 57.83 | |
Geoff Boycott | 56.83 | |
Ricky Ponting | 56.73 | |
Ranji | 56.37 | |
Bob Simpson | 56.22 | |
Wally Hammond | 56.10 | |
Rahul Dravid | 55.89 | |
Len Hutton | 55.81 |
Ranji is the only person on this list who made his first-class debut prior to 1920. In fact, he played nearly all his cricket before World War I. Now that was an era when an average of 35-40 used to be regarded as a very good record in first-class cricket.
I think these tables ought to be better known. Ranji was so much more than a mystical Oriental talent who played unorthodox strokes. He was, without doubt, the foremost batsman of his generation. In fact, it can be argued that Ranji was the most dominant and consistent batsman the world had seen until Bradman came along in the thirties.
Surely it's a career that deserves more recognition by cricket historians and greater mindshare among cricket fans (especially English cricket fans)!
Saturday, November 06, 2010
On Income "Inequality"
I stumbled upon an article lately on my Google Reader feed that ranted somewhat predictably about how income "inequality" has risen significantly in the United States and how the middle class in the US has stagnated over the past 2-3 decades. Here's the link
It is a very provocative article as most poorly reasoned articles are. The worst part of it is that the author attempts to place the blame for "inequality of incomes" on Corporate America without rhyme or reason. In this post, I ponder on the possible reasons for stagnation of middle-class incomes. There are several of them and the most obvious ones have nothing to do with Corporate America or conservative economic policies.
Let's look at certain portions of the article that are worthy of repudiation.
globalization's significant profits were captured by a small corporate elite in the U.S. and a new corporate elite and rising middle class in China and India. The American middle class got very little of it. No wonder people are mad.......Americans accept income and wealth inequality to a much larger degree than Europe........... Looking at the stats on inequality gives us an idea of why so many are angry at the business elite — it's the highest since the 20's and getting worse
Okay. So the moot point is that while incomes have soared in the top bracket, the "median" income of the "representative" Middle American has stagnated over the last few decades notwithstanding the outstanding economic growth during the same period.
I checked up the income stats on wikipedia and it appears that this contention is quite compelling on the surface.
We observe that while the 95th %ile income has risen by nearly 40% between 1979 and 2003, the median incomes have remained quite stagnant. On the surface, this might seem like an indictment of Reagan era deregulation and the increasing preponderance of economic conservatism in the US since the late seventies.
But there are several problems with this story.
Think about Individuals and not some mythical "Middle American" : Anybody with an iota of sense can readily see that the 50th %iler who earned a median income of $38,649 in 1979 is not necessarily from the same household as the 50th %iler who earned $43,318 in 2003. It is quite possible that someone who was at 50th %ile in 1979 now has a gainfully employed son who is closer to the 80th %ile on the income distribution curve.
The American Middle class has changed in constitution since the late seventies. Several households have moved up the economic ladder as one would expect in any society bustling with private economic activity. Then, the natural question is that if most households have been upwardly mobile over the past three decades, why have median incomes remained stagnant?? The answer could well be immigration.
Immigration likely to push down median Incomes: A lot of people emigrate to the US with the hope of working their way out of poverty in their native lands and entering the "middle class". These immigrants are often unskilled and poorly educated and hence unlikely to land up with jobs that fetch them more than the median US income.
Households that have immigrated in the eighties and nineties did not feature in the dataset that generated a median income of $38,649 in 1979. Which is why it is highly irregular and inappropriate to compare two very distinct datasets from 1979 and 2003 and make sweeping statements about stagnant "middle class" incomes in the country.
So, does that mean the US should place restriction on immigration to help solve this "problem" of seeming income inequality? No. Reducing inequality of incomes should never be an end in itself. Most recent immigrants to US earning less than the median income are quite happy with their adopted country and wouldn't want to return to their roots. Take for instance a waiter in an ethnic Indian restaurant in NYC (Saravana Bhavan for eg). The guy probably earns $20,000 in his present role which perhaps places him at the 40th %ile on the income distribution curve. It is quite likely that percentile-wise he was much better off in his native country, prior to immigration (given that median income in India is barely $500 p.a). Yet, immigration makes sense for this guy as he is better off being a 40th %iler in NYC than an 80th %iler in Trichy, TN.
The Tamil waiter's immigration to US has contributed to a drop in the median American income. Nevertheless, it is welcome as the waiter's immigration was a personal preference and leaves him better off than he otherwise would've been in his native town.
"Inequality" could be an outcome of personal choices : Let's consider Bob, a successful corporate executive of yesteryear who used to earn the equivalent of $300,000 back in 1979. He has a daughter - Alice who has led a rather comfortable life thanks to her father's affluence. Unlike her father, Alice has little aptitude for business. She has always evinced keen interest in Native American history and wants to specialize in the same and eventually end up as a professor of Native American history in one of the eastern colleges. Alice is 30 years old now in 2003 and is well settled in a Boston college enjoying her role thoroughly. Her annual income is in the vicinity of $50,000, not even one-fifth of what her father used to earn in 1979!!
Is this an instance of downward intergenerational mobility? Yes. Nevertheless, it is an outcome of personal preferences and shouldn't be bemoaned. Alice is less well off than her parents in terms of monthly cash-flow. But she loves her job and probably enjoys more leisure than her father ever did in all his working life!
This little story emphasises an important point that's often overlooked by liberals who bemoan income inequality :
"It is quite likely that the 50th %iler enjoys more leisure and leads a less stressful life than the 95th %iler!"
Distribution of Leisure fairer in recent decades : Back in 1900, the distribution of Leisure was terribly unfair in the Western world. The rich were not just wealthy in terms of cash but also leisure, with little accountability. The workers who slogged 18 hours a day in unwholesome sweatshops, had neither the income nor the leisure to compensate for the lack of income.
Today, the distribution of leisure is distinctly fairer. The clerk in a Federal office may languish at the 50th %ile of the income curve, but he is quite probably placed much better (perhaps 90th %ile+) on the leisure distribution curve! The corporate executives of today enjoy far less leisure and peace of mind than the landed gentry who constituted the affluent class in the 19th century.
Disclaimer : This is only a hypothesis. But I do wish someone undertakes a study that examines how the distribution of leisure has shifted over the past 100 years in favour of the lower income groups.
Writers in the press who talk about rising income inequality in America seldom think about the points discussed in this post because of their obsession with aggregate nation-wide statistics and an indifference to what the statistics actually mean in the context of average individuals and households. Which is why we keep reading pieces where "pundits" use statistics such as the ones used in this post to launch a tirade on outsourcing and corporate executive compensation.
Inequality of outcomes need not necessarily always be a plot hatched by Wall Street wolves or neo-conservative policy makers. People who think so misunderstand not just economics but also human nature. Economics is a social science that concerns real people gifted with a free will. To reduce these people to a statistical abstraction is not just downright unfair, but bad science.
|
I stumbled upon an article lately on my Google Reader feed that ranted somewhat predictably about how income "inequality" has risen significantly in the United States and how the middle class in the US has stagnated over the past 2-3 decades. Here's the link
It is a very provocative article as most poorly reasoned articles are. The worst part of it is that the author attempts to place the blame for "inequality of incomes" on Corporate America without rhyme or reason. In this post, I ponder on the possible reasons for stagnation of middle-class incomes. There are several of them and the most obvious ones have nothing to do with Corporate America or conservative economic policies.
Let's look at certain portions of the article that are worthy of repudiation.
globalization's significant profits were captured by a small corporate elite in the U.S. and a new corporate elite and rising middle class in China and India. The American middle class got very little of it. No wonder people are mad.......Americans accept income and wealth inequality to a much larger degree than Europe........... Looking at the stats on inequality gives us an idea of why so many are angry at the business elite — it's the highest since the 20's and getting worse
Okay. So the moot point is that while incomes have soared in the top bracket, the "median" income of the "representative" Middle American has stagnated over the last few decades notwithstanding the outstanding economic growth during the same period.
I checked up the income stats on wikipedia and it appears that this contention is quite compelling on the surface.
Sluggish Growth in Median American Incomes | ||
---|---|---|
Data | 2003 | 1979 |
Median (50th) | $43,318 | $38,649 |
95th percentile | $154,120 | $111,445 |
We observe that while the 95th %ile income has risen by nearly 40% between 1979 and 2003, the median incomes have remained quite stagnant. On the surface, this might seem like an indictment of Reagan era deregulation and the increasing preponderance of economic conservatism in the US since the late seventies.
But there are several problems with this story.
Think about Individuals and not some mythical "Middle American" : Anybody with an iota of sense can readily see that the 50th %iler who earned a median income of $38,649 in 1979 is not necessarily from the same household as the 50th %iler who earned $43,318 in 2003. It is quite possible that someone who was at 50th %ile in 1979 now has a gainfully employed son who is closer to the 80th %ile on the income distribution curve.
The American Middle class has changed in constitution since the late seventies. Several households have moved up the economic ladder as one would expect in any society bustling with private economic activity. Then, the natural question is that if most households have been upwardly mobile over the past three decades, why have median incomes remained stagnant?? The answer could well be immigration.
Immigration likely to push down median Incomes: A lot of people emigrate to the US with the hope of working their way out of poverty in their native lands and entering the "middle class". These immigrants are often unskilled and poorly educated and hence unlikely to land up with jobs that fetch them more than the median US income.
Households that have immigrated in the eighties and nineties did not feature in the dataset that generated a median income of $38,649 in 1979. Which is why it is highly irregular and inappropriate to compare two very distinct datasets from 1979 and 2003 and make sweeping statements about stagnant "middle class" incomes in the country.
So, does that mean the US should place restriction on immigration to help solve this "problem" of seeming income inequality? No. Reducing inequality of incomes should never be an end in itself. Most recent immigrants to US earning less than the median income are quite happy with their adopted country and wouldn't want to return to their roots. Take for instance a waiter in an ethnic Indian restaurant in NYC (Saravana Bhavan for eg). The guy probably earns $20,000 in his present role which perhaps places him at the 40th %ile on the income distribution curve. It is quite likely that percentile-wise he was much better off in his native country, prior to immigration (given that median income in India is barely $500 p.a). Yet, immigration makes sense for this guy as he is better off being a 40th %iler in NYC than an 80th %iler in Trichy, TN.
The Tamil waiter's immigration to US has contributed to a drop in the median American income. Nevertheless, it is welcome as the waiter's immigration was a personal preference and leaves him better off than he otherwise would've been in his native town.
"Inequality" could be an outcome of personal choices : Let's consider Bob, a successful corporate executive of yesteryear who used to earn the equivalent of $300,000 back in 1979. He has a daughter - Alice who has led a rather comfortable life thanks to her father's affluence. Unlike her father, Alice has little aptitude for business. She has always evinced keen interest in Native American history and wants to specialize in the same and eventually end up as a professor of Native American history in one of the eastern colleges. Alice is 30 years old now in 2003 and is well settled in a Boston college enjoying her role thoroughly. Her annual income is in the vicinity of $50,000, not even one-fifth of what her father used to earn in 1979!!
Is this an instance of downward intergenerational mobility? Yes. Nevertheless, it is an outcome of personal preferences and shouldn't be bemoaned. Alice is less well off than her parents in terms of monthly cash-flow. But she loves her job and probably enjoys more leisure than her father ever did in all his working life!
This little story emphasises an important point that's often overlooked by liberals who bemoan income inequality :
"It is quite likely that the 50th %iler enjoys more leisure and leads a less stressful life than the 95th %iler!"
Distribution of Leisure fairer in recent decades : Back in 1900, the distribution of Leisure was terribly unfair in the Western world. The rich were not just wealthy in terms of cash but also leisure, with little accountability. The workers who slogged 18 hours a day in unwholesome sweatshops, had neither the income nor the leisure to compensate for the lack of income.
Today, the distribution of leisure is distinctly fairer. The clerk in a Federal office may languish at the 50th %ile of the income curve, but he is quite probably placed much better (perhaps 90th %ile+) on the leisure distribution curve! The corporate executives of today enjoy far less leisure and peace of mind than the landed gentry who constituted the affluent class in the 19th century.
Disclaimer : This is only a hypothesis. But I do wish someone undertakes a study that examines how the distribution of leisure has shifted over the past 100 years in favour of the lower income groups.
Writers in the press who talk about rising income inequality in America seldom think about the points discussed in this post because of their obsession with aggregate nation-wide statistics and an indifference to what the statistics actually mean in the context of average individuals and households. Which is why we keep reading pieces where "pundits" use statistics such as the ones used in this post to launch a tirade on outsourcing and corporate executive compensation.
Inequality of outcomes need not necessarily always be a plot hatched by Wall Street wolves or neo-conservative policy makers. People who think so misunderstand not just economics but also human nature. Economics is a social science that concerns real people gifted with a free will. To reduce these people to a statistical abstraction is not just downright unfair, but bad science.
Labels: economics, statistics
Saturday, October 30, 2010
Puncturing Inflated Legends
Here's another cricket post!
I've been spending a lot of time on Cricinfo lately, where they've been busy compiling All Time XIs. These exercises are fun as they help you put the performances of current players into proper perspective by sparing some time to objectively judge bygone careers which are not fresh in the memory of the cricket watcher.
The passage of time often dims our memory of past players, to the extent that we're very unlikely to appraise them on their merits. Certain cricketers are unfairly forgotten as the years roll by since their once-impressive career records achieved under more challenging circumstances appear less flashy today - an era which has generally been kinder to batsmen. Certain other past cricketers are more fortunate. They end up occupying disproportionate mindshare thanks to legends that inflate with time!
This post concerns a cricketer of the latter kind - a top-class opening bat of his time who has gathered a somewhat undeserved reputation as one of the greatest batsmen of all time thanks to poorly remembered legends. Sunil Gavaskar.
Gavaskar's inflated reputation rests on his seemingly outstanding record against the premier team of his era which possessed a four-pronged pace attack - the West Indies. He averaged about 65 runs per test innings against them with 13 Hundreds! Seven of them in the West Indies. I encountered these stats about a decade back when my obsession with cricket was far greater than it is today and I was busy devouring any form of cricket literature.
My initial reaction was awe, but it was soon tinged with doubt and scepticism. Something was amiss I wondered. I didn't think it was quite likely for anybody to make that many big scores against an attack consisting of Andy Roberts, Michael Holding, Joel Garner and Malcolm Marshall.
Thanks to Cricinfo Statsguru, I now discover that my doubts were well founded. Gavaskar played six Test series in all against the West Indies. Here's a summary of his performance in each of them.
Very Impressive on first sight. But distinctly less impressive if someone actually bothers to visit the scorecards!
Let's briefly examine what Gavaskar had to contend with in each of these series.
1970/71 : This was Gavaskar's debut series. Probably the most outstanding series return for any batsman making his debut, in the history of Test cricket. The West Indian team he was up against was far from formidable. It was a team in transition captained by an ageing Sobers. The bowling attack was composed of Vanburn Holder (career bowling avg : 33.27), Shillingford (avg : 35.8), Noreiga (avg: 29.0) and Sobers himself (avg : 34.03).
The era of Roberts, Holding and Co was still 3-4 years away. I know it might sound a little churlish to grudge Gavaskar his accolades. Averaging 150+ over 4 games is an achievement in any form of the game, be it Tests or club cricket, especially for a 22 year old batsman. However, it is quite unlikely that Gavaskar on debut would've achieved similar results against the West Indian attack of the early eighties!
1974/75: Gavaskar only played in two of the five test matches owing to injury. And he wasn't particularly successful against an attack spearheaded by the great Andy Roberts in the two test matches that he did play in. Note : West Indies was still some distance away from their era of fast bowling glory. Roberts had already announced himself. But the rest of the quartet were yet to make their test debuts. Gavaskar's friend and brother-in-law GR Viswanath was a lot more successful against Roberts in this series winning two test matches almost single-handedly at Kolkata and Chennai.
1975/76 : Gavaskar did well in this series with two hundreds, including a match winning knock enabling India chase a 400+ target on the fifth day! Nevertheless, it is worth remembering that the record chase was achieved against an attack that was somewhat mediocre barring Michael Holding. The rest of the attack included B.Julien (avg: 37), AL Padmore (avg: 135), Imtiaz Ali (avg: 44.5) and R.Jumadeen(avg: 39.3). That's the kind of attack against which even a flat-track bully like Yuvraj Singh will fancy his chances.
1978/79 : Now, this was a rewarding home series for Sunny in which he harvested four hundreds! But, mind you, this was against a weakened West Indian touring party thanks to Kerry Packer! I grant that the great Malcolm Marshall was around. But hang on. This was his debut series!
The other bowlers whom Gavaskar flayed round the park were ST Clarke (avg: 28), N Philip (avg: 37) and Vanburn Holder (avg: 33). Hardly terrors on subcontinental pitches.
1982-83: Ah. Now, for the first time, Sunny Gavaskar was pitted against a full strength West Indian attack in the West Indies, with Holding, Roberts, Garner and Marshall operating simultaneously. Sunny averaged a paltry 30 over five tests.
1983/84: Here, I must give credit where it is due. He was up against some very formidable bowlers. Holding, Roberts and Marshall. Sunny acquitted himself well with a healthy average of 50, including an unbeaten 236* at Chennai in the final test. Nevertheless, the average of 50 looks flattering thanks to that unbeaten double century.
Sunil Gavaskar was one of the great Indian batsmen. Arguably the finest Indian bat of his generation. But his record against the WI is made to look more brilliant than it actually is thanks to some pretty easy pickings against weakened Carribean attacks on flat pitches.
His record against the full-strength West Indian attack of the early eighties is somewhat sketchy, not necessarily better than that of other great players of that generation against the same attack.
And yet, I invariably find pundits of all hues championing Gavaskar as one of the top 2-3 opening batsmen in the history of Test cricket! That may not be an altogether unreasonable claim, given that the guy scored over 10,000 Test runs and lasted nearly two decades at the highest level. But it is definitely not very easy to sustain that claim based solely on his record against the West Indies!
|
Here's another cricket post!
I've been spending a lot of time on Cricinfo lately, where they've been busy compiling All Time XIs. These exercises are fun as they help you put the performances of current players into proper perspective by sparing some time to objectively judge bygone careers which are not fresh in the memory of the cricket watcher.
The passage of time often dims our memory of past players, to the extent that we're very unlikely to appraise them on their merits. Certain cricketers are unfairly forgotten as the years roll by since their once-impressive career records achieved under more challenging circumstances appear less flashy today - an era which has generally been kinder to batsmen. Certain other past cricketers are more fortunate. They end up occupying disproportionate mindshare thanks to legends that inflate with time!
This post concerns a cricketer of the latter kind - a top-class opening bat of his time who has gathered a somewhat undeserved reputation as one of the greatest batsmen of all time thanks to poorly remembered legends. Sunil Gavaskar.
Gavaskar's inflated reputation rests on his seemingly outstanding record against the premier team of his era which possessed a four-pronged pace attack - the West Indies. He averaged about 65 runs per test innings against them with 13 Hundreds! Seven of them in the West Indies. I encountered these stats about a decade back when my obsession with cricket was far greater than it is today and I was busy devouring any form of cricket literature.
My initial reaction was awe, but it was soon tinged with doubt and scepticism. Something was amiss I wondered. I didn't think it was quite likely for anybody to make that many big scores against an attack consisting of Andy Roberts, Michael Holding, Joel Garner and Malcolm Marshall.
Thanks to Cricinfo Statsguru, I now discover that my doubts were well founded. Gavaskar played six Test series in all against the West Indies. Here's a summary of his performance in each of them.
Average | |
---|---|
1970/71 in West Indies | 154.8 |
1974/75 in India | 27 |
1975/76 in West Indies | 55.7 |
1978/79 in India | 91.5 |
1982/83 in West Indies | 30 |
1983/84 in India | 50.5 |
Very Impressive on first sight. But distinctly less impressive if someone actually bothers to visit the scorecards!
Let's briefly examine what Gavaskar had to contend with in each of these series.
1970/71 : This was Gavaskar's debut series. Probably the most outstanding series return for any batsman making his debut, in the history of Test cricket. The West Indian team he was up against was far from formidable. It was a team in transition captained by an ageing Sobers. The bowling attack was composed of Vanburn Holder (career bowling avg : 33.27), Shillingford (avg : 35.8), Noreiga (avg: 29.0) and Sobers himself (avg : 34.03).
The era of Roberts, Holding and Co was still 3-4 years away. I know it might sound a little churlish to grudge Gavaskar his accolades. Averaging 150+ over 4 games is an achievement in any form of the game, be it Tests or club cricket, especially for a 22 year old batsman. However, it is quite unlikely that Gavaskar on debut would've achieved similar results against the West Indian attack of the early eighties!
1974/75: Gavaskar only played in two of the five test matches owing to injury. And he wasn't particularly successful against an attack spearheaded by the great Andy Roberts in the two test matches that he did play in. Note : West Indies was still some distance away from their era of fast bowling glory. Roberts had already announced himself. But the rest of the quartet were yet to make their test debuts. Gavaskar's friend and brother-in-law GR Viswanath was a lot more successful against Roberts in this series winning two test matches almost single-handedly at Kolkata and Chennai.
1975/76 : Gavaskar did well in this series with two hundreds, including a match winning knock enabling India chase a 400+ target on the fifth day! Nevertheless, it is worth remembering that the record chase was achieved against an attack that was somewhat mediocre barring Michael Holding. The rest of the attack included B.Julien (avg: 37), AL Padmore (avg: 135), Imtiaz Ali (avg: 44.5) and R.Jumadeen(avg: 39.3). That's the kind of attack against which even a flat-track bully like Yuvraj Singh will fancy his chances.
1978/79 : Now, this was a rewarding home series for Sunny in which he harvested four hundreds! But, mind you, this was against a weakened West Indian touring party thanks to Kerry Packer! I grant that the great Malcolm Marshall was around. But hang on. This was his debut series!
The other bowlers whom Gavaskar flayed round the park were ST Clarke (avg: 28), N Philip (avg: 37) and Vanburn Holder (avg: 33). Hardly terrors on subcontinental pitches.
1982-83: Ah. Now, for the first time, Sunny Gavaskar was pitted against a full strength West Indian attack in the West Indies, with Holding, Roberts, Garner and Marshall operating simultaneously. Sunny averaged a paltry 30 over five tests.
1983/84: Here, I must give credit where it is due. He was up against some very formidable bowlers. Holding, Roberts and Marshall. Sunny acquitted himself well with a healthy average of 50, including an unbeaten 236* at Chennai in the final test. Nevertheless, the average of 50 looks flattering thanks to that unbeaten double century.
Sunil Gavaskar was one of the great Indian batsmen. Arguably the finest Indian bat of his generation. But his record against the WI is made to look more brilliant than it actually is thanks to some pretty easy pickings against weakened Carribean attacks on flat pitches.
His record against the full-strength West Indian attack of the early eighties is somewhat sketchy, not necessarily better than that of other great players of that generation against the same attack.
And yet, I invariably find pundits of all hues championing Gavaskar as one of the top 2-3 opening batsmen in the history of Test cricket! That may not be an altogether unreasonable claim, given that the guy scored over 10,000 Test runs and lasted nearly two decades at the highest level. But it is definitely not very easy to sustain that claim based solely on his record against the West Indies!
Labels: cricket
Sunday, October 10, 2010
Play back or Drive
The ongoing India-Australia Test series has marked my resumption of Test match viewing, after having practically lost all interest in the game over the past 4-5 years.
This post was prompted by Michael Clarke's soft dismissal by Harbhajan in the first innings of the Bangalore Test yesterday.
One of the most ungainly features of modern batsmanship is the almost instinctive lunge forward while defending a slow bowler. To my mind, it seems like a nothing shot. The forward lurch does not necessarily get you to the pitch of the ball. Also, it deprives you of the extra instant of time to judge the delivery.
The key to playing spin bowling well is to use your feet to reduce the element of uncertainty. There are two ways in which one can meet that objective -
By lurching forward, you're only making an offer of a bat-pad dismissal every ball!
And yet, this most ungainly of strokes has been inexplicably popular across the world for as long as I can remember. I wonder if there was ever a time in cricket history when the forward defensive was not in fashion!
And yes. It is particularly disappointing when batsmen of the calibre of Ponting and Clarke commit batting suicide by lurching forward.
These thoughts made me scour the net for similar polemics against the "forward defensive". Here's a video clipping of Don Bradman's defensive play in one of the 1938 Ashes tests. Check out the section from 1:45mins to 2:05 mins. What struck me was that the guy does not show any inclination to lunge forward. Instead, he plays back as a rule even if the delivery is not exactly short in length. No wonder he seldom got out caught at forward short-leg or silly point.
I thought it was a very good demonstration of how to defend against slow bowlers.
|
The ongoing India-Australia Test series has marked my resumption of Test match viewing, after having practically lost all interest in the game over the past 4-5 years.
This post was prompted by Michael Clarke's soft dismissal by Harbhajan in the first innings of the Bangalore Test yesterday.
One of the most ungainly features of modern batsmanship is the almost instinctive lunge forward while defending a slow bowler. To my mind, it seems like a nothing shot. The forward lurch does not necessarily get you to the pitch of the ball. Also, it deprives you of the extra instant of time to judge the delivery.
The key to playing spin bowling well is to use your feet to reduce the element of uncertainty. There are two ways in which one can meet that objective -
By getting to the pitch of the ball
In which case it does not really matter how much spin the bowler has imparted to it.
By playing back!
When in doubt, one must always play back. If it isn't possible to get to the pitch of the ball, the batsman must always play late which helps him buy an extra second to examine the extent of deviation off the pitch.
By lurching forward, you're only making an offer of a bat-pad dismissal every ball!
And yet, this most ungainly of strokes has been inexplicably popular across the world for as long as I can remember. I wonder if there was ever a time in cricket history when the forward defensive was not in fashion!
And yes. It is particularly disappointing when batsmen of the calibre of Ponting and Clarke commit batting suicide by lurching forward.
These thoughts made me scour the net for similar polemics against the "forward defensive". Here's a video clipping of Don Bradman's defensive play in one of the 1938 Ashes tests. Check out the section from 1:45mins to 2:05 mins. What struck me was that the guy does not show any inclination to lunge forward. Instead, he plays back as a rule even if the delivery is not exactly short in length. No wonder he seldom got out caught at forward short-leg or silly point.
I thought it was a very good demonstration of how to defend against slow bowlers.
Labels: cricket
Saturday, May 29, 2010
On why our bank deposits earn even less income than a Risk-free Government bond
This was a question that had been vexing me for quite a while. My savings deposit earns an interest of 3.5% a year. Whereas, the 90 day Government bill issued by the Indian Government earns about 5% p.a currently.
Shouldn't my salary account at a risk-ridden private bank yield me an income that atleast exceeds what can be earned by holding a "risk-free" 3 month government security?
Irving Fisher, the American Economist of the early 20th century, provides the answer in his opening chapter of The Theory of Interest published in 1930.
Reading this unpretentious prose is a bit like being present at the invention of something new - like the discovery of fire or the invention of the wheel. I love the way he uses the term "pure" instead of the cliched modern phrase "risk-free". Also, I love the very broad-minded definition of the term "chance". Back in B-school, we invariably used to think of sigma (the standard deviation of cash flows) when the word "chance" was mentioned. Fisher is delightfully free from all the jargon conventions that bind us.
Most importantly, he manages to answer the question posed in the beginning of the post. There is some merit in reading 80 year old classics once in a while
|
This was a question that had been vexing me for quite a while. My savings deposit earns an interest of 3.5% a year. Whereas, the 90 day Government bill issued by the Indian Government earns about 5% p.a currently.
Shouldn't my salary account at a risk-ridden private bank yield me an income that atleast exceeds what can be earned by holding a "risk-free" 3 month government security?
Irving Fisher, the American Economist of the early 20th century, provides the answer in his opening chapter of The Theory of Interest published in 1930.
While any exact and practical definition of a pure rate of interest is impossible, we may say roughly that the pure rate is the rate on loans which are practically devoid of chance. In particular, there are two chances which should thus be eliminated. One tends to raise the rate, namely the chance of default. The other tends to lower it, namely, the chance to use the security as a substitute for ready cash. In short, we thus rule out, on the one hand, all risky loans, and on the other, all bank deposits, subject to withdrawal on demand, even if accorded some interest...
Reading this unpretentious prose is a bit like being present at the invention of something new - like the discovery of fire or the invention of the wheel. I love the way he uses the term "pure" instead of the cliched modern phrase "risk-free". Also, I love the very broad-minded definition of the term "chance". Back in B-school, we invariably used to think of sigma (the standard deviation of cash flows) when the word "chance" was mentioned. Fisher is delightfully free from all the jargon conventions that bind us.
Most importantly, he manages to answer the question posed in the beginning of the post. There is some merit in reading 80 year old classics once in a while
Labels: economics